Help


[permalink] [id link]
+
Page "Environmental economics" ¶ 21
from Wikipedia
Edit
Promote Demote Fragment Fix

Some Related Sentences

Coase and Theorem
* Coase Theorem: A Study In Economic Epistemology, 1992 ISBN 0-930464-61-3
" Why Not a Political Coase Theorem?
This result, often known as the Coase Theorem, requires that
The case of the vaccinations would also not satisfy the requirements of the Coase Theorem.
However, the Coase Theorem is difficult to implement because Coase does not offer a negotiation method. Additionally, firms could potentially bribe each other since there is little to no government interaction under the Coase Theorem.
The Coase Theorem has been used by jurists and legal scholars in the analysis and resolution of disputes involving both contract law and tort law.
By applying the Coase Theorem two possible solutions arise for internalizing this externality.
* A simple illustration of the Coase Theorem
* Dilbert and the Coase Theorem ' The Coase theorem fails in the presence of asymmetric information.
* The Coase Theorem by Seth J. Chandler, The Wolfram Demonstrations Project.
Some economists argue from the Coase Theorem that, if industries internalized the costs of negative externalities they would face an incentive to reduce them, perhaps even becoming enthusiastic about taking advantage of opportunities to improve profitability through lower costs.
Experimental Test of the endowment effect and the Coase Theorem.
* Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., Thaler, R. H. " Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem " ( 1990 ) Journal of Political Economy, 98 ( 6 ), 1325-1348.

Coase and property
What Coase proposed in 1959 was that as long as property rights in these frequencies were well defined, it ultimately did not matter if adjacent radio stations interfered with each other by broadcasting in the same frequency band.
As a result, one normative conclusion sometimes drawn from the Coase theorem is that property rights should initially be assigned to the actors gaining the most utility from them.
Loss aversion and the endowment effect lead to a violation of the Coase theorem — that " the allocation of resources will be independent of the assignment of property rights when costless trades are possible " ( p. 1326 ).
This proposition is based on the assumption of Coase theorem, that is, with well-defined property rights, the free market will generally allocate resources to their most efficient use as long as transaction costs are low.

Coase and rights
While the exact definition of the Coase theorem remains unsettled, there are two issues or claims within the theorem: the results will be efficient and the results in terms of resource allocation will be the same regardless of initial assignments of rights / liabilities.

Coase and will
When transaction costs are low, the Coase theorem says that the political marketplace ( the decisions of the legislatures ) will allocate resources to the highest valued point ( Coase 1960 ).
With low transaction costs, the Coase theorem will come into play.
This counterintuitive insight — that the initial imposition of legal entitlement is irrelevant because the parties will eventually reach the same result — is Coase ’ s invariance thesis.
The Coase theorem considers all four of these outcomes logical because the economic incentives will be stronger than legal incentives.
Views on the relative merits of qualitative and quantitative models vary across the profession: Milton Friedman can be viewed as having advocated a qualitative approach, while Ronald Coase worried that " if you torture the data long enough, it will confess ;" Prospect theory as proposed by Daniel Kahneman ( a Nobel prize winner ) is more quantiative, while rational agent models are more qualitative.

Coase and optimal
Coase argues that the size of a firm ( as measured by how many contractual relations are " internal " to the firm and how many " external ") is a result of finding an optimal balance between the competing tendencies of the costs outlined above.

Coase and solution
The coasian solution, named for the economist Ronald Coase and unrelated to his Coase theorem, proposes a mechanism by which potential beneficiaries of a public good band together and pool their resources based on their willingness to pay to create the public good.
Once the optimum solution is implemented, Coase argues that the tax should not change, regardless of changing circumstances.

Coase and regardless
Coase said that regardless of whether the judge ruled that the sweetmaker had to stop using his machinery, or that the doctor had to put up with it, they could strike a mutually beneficial bargain that reaches the same outcome of resource distribution.

Coase and who
Economists who studied with Hayek at the LSE in the 1930s and the 1940s include Arthur Lewis, Ronald Coase, John Kenneth Galbraith, Abba Lerner, Nicholas Kaldor, George Shackle, Thomas Balogh, Vera Smith, L. K. Jha, Arthur Seldon, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, and Oskar Lange.
The term " transaction cost " is frequently thought to have been coined by Ronald Coase, who used it to develop a theoretical framework for predicting when certain economic tasks would be performed by firms, and when they would be performed on the market.
Kenneth Arrow, Ronald Coase and Douglass North are some of the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel winners who are known for their sympathy to the field.
Because Ronald Coase himself did not originally intend to set forth any one particular theorem, it has largely been the effort of others who have developed the loose formulation of the Coase theorem.
Among the individuals who have attended, graduated, and taught at the University are astronaut Ellen S. Baker, American journalist Wolf Blitzer, CEO and founder of the History Channel Abbe Raven, CEO of Paramount Pictures Brad Grey, CEO and founder of Baidu Robin Li, Pulitzer Prize-winner Tom Toles, Nobel Prize-winners, Ronald Coase, Herbert A. Hauptman and Sir John Carew Eccles.

Coase and if
Ronald Coase argued that if all parties involved can easily organize payments so as to pay each other for their actions, then an efficient outcome can be reached without government intervention.
Coase ( 1960 ) argued that if the transaction costs between potential beneficiaries of a public good are sufficiently low, and it is therefore easy for beneficiaries to find each other and pool their money based on the public good's value to themselves, then an adequate level of public goods production can occur even under competitive free market conditions.
The social harm gets worse, Coase argues, if only one offender pays for the social harm.
Ronald Coase suggests that if Smith's earlier proposal of granting colonies representation in the British parliament proportional to their contributions to public revenues had been followed, " there would have been no 1776, ... America would now be ruling England, and we America would be today celebrating Adam Smith not simply as the author of the Wealth of Nations, but hailing him as a founding father.

Coase and transaction
Second, technological changes, particularly the dramatic fall in information communication costs, which are a significant component of transaction costs, have led to changes in coordination among the members of the supply chain network ( Coase, 1998 ).
Ronald Coase, one of the movement's principal proponents, submitted, in his article The Problem of Social Cost ( 1960 ), that the aim of tort should be to reflect as closely as possible liability where transaction costs should be minimized.
Coase noted, however, that there are a number of transaction costs to using the market ; the cost of obtaining a good or service via the market is actually more than just the price of the good.
While he did not coin the specific term, Coase indeed discussed " costs of using the price mechanism " in his 1937 paper The Nature of the Firm, where he first discusses the concept of transaction costs, and refers to the " Costs of Market Transactions " in his seminal work, The Problem of Social Cost ( 1960 ).
Ronald Coase set out his transaction cost theory of the firm in 1937, making it one of the first ( neo-classical ) attempts to define the firm theoretically in relation to the market.
From the Chicago school of economics, Ronald Coase introduced the notion of transaction costs into the understanding of why firms are founded and how they continue to behave.
This economic theorem, along with his 1937 paper on the nature of the firm ( which also emphasizes the role of transaction costs ), earned Ronald Coase the 1991 Nobel Prize in Economics.
In this paper, Coase argued that real-world transaction costs are rarely low enough to allow for efficient bargaining and hence the theorem is almost always inapplicable to economic reality.
In his UCLA dissertation and in subsequent work, Steven N. S. Cheung ( 1969 ) coined an equivalence version of the Coase theorem: aside from transaction costs, all institutional forms are capable of achieving the same efficient allocation.
In resultant scholarship using economic models of analysis, prominently including the Coase theorem, theoretical models demonstrated that, when transaction costs are minimized or nonexistent, the legal appropriation of liability diminishes in importance or disappears completely.
Economist Ronald Coase argued that individuals can come to an agreement with an efficient result without the interference of a third party when transaction costs are low.
However, critics have charged that the " theorem " attributed to Coase is of extremely limited practicability because of assumptions, including that it was theorized to account for adjacent effects where transaction costs for bargaining agents are typically small, but is ill-suited to real world externalities which have high bargaining costs due to many factors.

0.149 seconds.